California Experiments with New Ways of Pricing Electricity
By Ahmad Faruqui, PhD
Danville, California


In 1998, California restructured its power market, hoping to reduce its electricity prices that were 50 percent higher than the US average. The administration of then Governor Pete Wilson wished to promote job creation in the state, by reversing the flight of industry to other states. The state had been hit hard by the recession of 1991 and the cutbacks in defense spending that had ensued following the end of the Gulf War.

Much to everyone’s surprise, the restructuring experiment ended in failure just two years later. As wholesale prices shot through the roof, the power market experienced a “melt down.” Blackouts were frequent. Since retail rates had been frozen under the restructuring plan, the investor-owned utilities would lose money every month, since they had been forced into the unenviable position of “buying high and selling low.” This ultimately impaired their credit worthiness and forced Governor Gray Davis into the power business.

The state signed long-term contracts with unregulated power producers. While this eliminated the near term threat of blackouts, it proved to be an expensive mistake as it converted California’s long-standing budget surplus into a large deficit. Not too long afterwards, Arnold Schwarzenegger replaced Gray Davis as the state’s governor in a recall election, reflecting voter anger at Davis.

The failure of California’s market restructuring program dealt a body blow to power market restructuring efforts worldwide. Seeking to contain the problem, the World Bank, which had long been a proponent of introducing competition into power markets by restructuring them, issued a policy paper stating that the problem lay not with market restructuring but with California’s specific market design. This design, among other failings, had disconnected the demand side of the market from the supply side by eliminating pricing flexibility in retail markets. In other words, there was no “demand response” in the markets, giving a free rein to unregulated power producers to charge high prices.

Five years ago this month, California experienced unusually hot weather conditions. This happened at a time of diminished hydro supplies in the Pacific Northwest, which provided a quarter of California’s electricity. Both events coincided with a surge in the price of natural gas, which fueled three quarters of California’s power plants, creating what was appropriately termed a “perfect storm” in the electricity market. Against this backdrop, wholesale prices rose ten fold and stayed high for several months.

Electricity costs are highest during hot summer afternoons when central air conditioners raised power demand to peak levels. But even were it legally feasible, there was no way to send retail electricity customers higher prices during those times, since traditional electric meters cannot measure electricity consumption by time of day. Ironically, the digital revolution that was spawned in California’s Silicon Valley bypassed these meters, which continued to embody 50-year old technology. Peak load pricing would have given customers an incentive to lower loads during peak times that, in turn, would have reduced prices in wholesale markets. However, peak load pricing requires the installation of digital interval meters. By refusing to change its meters, the state ended up paying several times more for procuring expensive power.

In the aftermath of the crisis, the state was forced to raise retail rates for most customers, the very opposite of the intent of restructuring. Large residential customers ended up seeing their electric bills rise by upwards of 30 percent. However, since they had no economic incentive to use less power during peak times, the state funded a very expensive advertising program called “Flex Your Power” that asked them to voluntarily reduce power demand during peak times. In addition, through emergency legislation, it decided to spend $34 million on the installation of digital meters on all large commercial and industrial customers.

California also began to assess the potential for reducing peak loads in smaller commercial and industrial customers and, most notably, in residential customers. Since it was not clear whether such customers would be able to reduce peak loads, it initiated a scientifically-designed social experiment with some 2,500 customers.

The experiment ran from July 2003 and December 2004 and its report (which I co-authored) has been released recently. It quantifies the impact of several new rates, including a critical-peak pricing (CPP) rate. The CPP rate, while featuring the same average price annually as the standard rate, has higher prices during the peak period and lower prices during the off-peak period. The peak period runs from 2 to 7 in the afternoon on non-holiday weekdays and features prices that are about twice as high as the standard rate. All other hours are off-peak and feature prices that are lower than the standard rate. On 15 critical days, the peak price was raised so it was five times higher than the standard rate, to simulate market conditions that might be encountered during a crisis.

The study found that residential customers in California reduced peak period energy use by about 14 percent in response to a CPP rate. Impacts on peak-period energy use on critical days did not differ significantly across the summers of 2003 and 2004. However, impacts were higher during the hot summer months of July through September than during the milder summer months of May, June and October. Winter impacts were lower than summer impacts. Impacts were lower during the milder winter months of November, March and April than during the colder months of December, January and February.

Prior to the experiment, some experts had argued that there would be a degradation of demand response if multiple critical days were called in a row. The experimental results showed that this did not occur. There was also a question about whether technologies such as smart thermostats (that automatically raise the temperature setting when prices rise) enhanced impacts. The experiment found this was indeed the case. Reductions in peak loads exceeded 25 percent for customers that were given enabling technology.

These new experimental results are being used by California’s three investor-owned utilities to develop business cases for advanced metering infrastructure that is estimated to cost several billion dollars for their 10 million residential customers. The California Public Utilities Commission is in the process of reviewing the business cases and is expected to announce a final decision later in the year.

Consistent with the state’s reputation as a global bellwether, California’s pricing experiment and the utility business cases are being studied intently around the world. So, while its grand experiment with market restructuring did not succeed, the Golden State’s well-designed experiment with electricity pricing is on track for success.

 

------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Editor: Akhtar M. Faruqui
© 2004 pakistanlink.com . All Rights Reserved.